Jun 04, 2008
Apr 28, 2013
Sep 20, 2009
Sep 29, 2008
Aug 24, 2012
Dec 13, 2009

Is There an Icon for Everything?

It may have started with this:

180px-smileysvg.png

Search for “icon” on LexisNexis and you can quickly overload the browser with thousands of citations. And no wonder, the word appears continually these days in every section of the newspaper. Yesterday the Chicago Tribune reported, “At Hall of Fame, Day Dedicated to Two Icons, Not Controversy.” Who were the two titans of the game? Iron man Cal Ripken was one; the other was Tony Gwynn. A fine player, I’m sure, but not exactly a household name. He is, however, probably in the same league as Tom Snyder, who today was labeled a “late-night talk show icon.” A search reveals the same for a clerk in Cambridge, a banker in Arkansas, and just about everything in Australia. Not to mention tomato soup in the U.S. . . . Should we be surprised that there now also are “supericons” (Kate Moss, by one account)?

One might wonder why. My Northwestern colleagues Pablo Bockowski and James Webster have each done research that suggests one answer to the proliferation of “icon.” Very briefly, the combination of new media and intense competition for consumer attention can produce homogenized content. YouTube is an obvious example: of all those video clips seen by millions of viewers, one result is that a very few get tremendous circulation–dare we say they become iconic?–while most fade unseen in the desert air. As all media become focused on relaying what is currently popular to get their share of consumer attention, this phenomenon becomes the standard of significance while “repurposing” pops up as a new (and ugly) verb.

Here’s where “icon” comes into the picture. The homogenization thesis is a corrective to the fragmentation thesis, which says that incredible proliferation in media technologies and producers creates ever more finely segmented and isolated audiences. Thus, fragmentation and homogenization are countervailing forces that can produce mixed outcomes. We might speculate that the homogenization that can happen across producers and audiences can also happen within any topical category, audience, or sub-culture: amidst the information explosion within that “locality,” some few individuals will get a disproportionate amount of attention and thus seem to be representative of the category. Given these market forces, being notable and being well-known will seem to be much the same, so much so that one word might suffice for both. And so it is that anyone trying to claim that anything is worth our attention might say that it is iconic.

Thus, the same word can mark two related though quite different qualities. “Icon” can refer to anything that is recognized widely, such as the smiley face, or to any representative of a particular sub-culture, such as Tony Gwynn.

Have a nice day.


Digg!

Share

Is There an Icon for Everything?

Discussion

1 Response

  1. Randall Bush says

    A lot of this depends on what we’re trying to extract and connate by our use of “icon.” As you’ve said, it’s true that both usage and presentation each can justify the moniker in popular culture; but highlighting these doesn’t change the deployment of the term. I’m not even sure it’s the term icon that matters at all, but instead teasing out whether or not we can really understand moments of reception in a general way any longer. To me, it quickly becomes very difficult to understand whether or not “icon” has been pasted on retroactively to a widely circulated social phenomena.

    I say this because I’m uneasy about Bockowski and Webster’s description (or the gloss of it, at least), one that equates presentation with meaning/reception, and by extension, market homogenization with popularity. It’s not clear to me that consumer society (or at least the most present portions of it) functions in this way. For example: Coke doesn’t dominate because whenever we see a can or a billboard, we rush out and buy it; and it’s not that Coke drills holes into our heads and crowds out alternatives unbeknownst to us; instead, I think it is because it (however minimally) changes the equation by which liberal qualities of choice are made, while never leaving the bounds of that equation (here, choice). I think this is very different than what’s described above, which almost equates product placement with iconicity. The larger point is that there’s a third term operating here, one that shouldn’t necessarily be about pinning down a definition of iconicity.

    -Randall

Leave A Reply

Your email address will not be published. Required fields are marked *

This site uses Akismet to reduce spam. Learn how your comment data is processed.